Manufacturer Rebates in a Green Supply Chain with Hybrid Production

Zhibing LIN, Lingmin DAI, Mofan CHEN

Journal of Systems Science and Information ›› 2022, Vol. 10 ›› Issue (2) : 130-149.

PDF(270 KB)
PDF(270 KB)
Journal of Systems Science and Information ›› 2022, Vol. 10 ›› Issue (2) : 130-149. DOI: 10.21078/JSSI-2022-130-20
 

Manufacturer Rebates in a Green Supply Chain with Hybrid Production

Author information +
History +

Abstract

This paper studies two manufacturer rebate strategies in a green supply chain. The results show that: 1) Irrespective of the type of rebate strategy used, channel members benefit; 2) Rebates for green products improve the green level of green products; 3) The more significant the slippage effects are, the more beneficial the rebate strategies are, for channel members. On this basis, the model is expanded to consider asymmetric potential market demands and asymmetric product substitution rates, respectively. The results show that the product substitution rate does not affect the strategic preference of channel members, but the potential market demand does.

Key words

Stackelberg game / manufacturer rebates / supply chain management / green level

Cite this article

Download Citations
Zhibing LIN , Lingmin DAI , Mofan CHEN. Manufacturer Rebates in a Green Supply Chain with Hybrid Production. Journal of Systems Science and Information, 2022, 10(2): 130-149 https://doi.org/10.21078/JSSI-2022-130-20

1 Introduction

With the rapid growth of the global economy, people's living standards worldwide have greatly improved. However, environmental problems such as pollution and global warming are becoming increasingly grave. According to a report released by the International Energy Agency in September 2019, global carbon dioxide emissions reached 32.8 billion tons in 2017, and environmental pollution has become one of the most urgent issues facing the world[1]. The United Nations Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change estimates that by 2099, the surface temperature of the earth will be eight degrees Celsius higher than it was in 1999[2]. To reduce environmental pollution, the Society of Manufacturing Engineers proposed the concept of green manufacturing in 1996[3]. Since then, many of the world's largest economies and companies have also participated in green manufacturing. For example, General Motors Company achieved full-cycle production at its Detroit tooling plant in 2007, in which 100% of the plant's waste materials and emissions can now be recycled in the production process[4]. At the same time, with the concept of environmental protection gradually creeping into the public consciousness, consumers are increasingly choosing green products. It has been reported that 75% of European consumers are willing to pay higher prices for environmentally friendly products[5]. However, as new products, green products have no absolute advantage in competing with conventional products and are even at a disadvantage in some aspects. For example, compared with fuel-powered vehicles, electric vehicles are often at a disadvantage in terms of mileage and price, which severely hinders their sales. As of January 17, 2020, the Gasgoo listed on its website that, from July to September 2019, monthly sales of new energy vehicles in China fell by 4.7%, 15.8%, and 18%, respectively.
To improve the market competitiveness of products, enterprises often offer promotions (advertisements, rebates, etc.). In the 1970s, Procter & Gamble Company (P & G) took the lead in sales promotions by issuing rebate coupons to consumers. Since then, an increasing number of manufacturers and retailers have used rebates as a strategy to attract and retain customers. For example, as of October 20, 2015, the Amazon(Z.CN) listed on its website that Amazon(Z.CN) used "F coin rebates", in which consumers place orders at the original price on the rebate network, and then are issued rebates approximately two months after the order is received and confirmed, with the rebates being in the form of an F coin, forcing consumers to go through a similar platform for their next purchase to redeem the F coin. Rebate strategies that reduce the price in the short term to improve product sales without changing the label price are widely used by companies. In fact, Chen, et al.[6] found that if not all consumers redeem the rebates, manufacturer rebates are beneficial to channel members. The slow extension of green products and the effectiveness of manufacturer rebates in the conventional products market motive us to introduce the manufacturer rebates in the green products market and examine the effects of manufacturer rebates.

2 Literature Review

Rebate strategies can be divided into two categories, depending on the objective, with one for enterprises and one for consumers. The rebates for enterprises, also known as channel rebates, are transfer payments offered from the manufacturer to the retailer based on the final sales or order quantities. For example, Taylor[7] studied the impacts of linear rebates and target rebates on supply chain decisions. Ha, et al.[8] constructed a model with two competing manufacturers and a common retailer and found that intense competition makes manufacturers reduce the rebate value or even stop offering rebates. Muzaffar, et al.[9] studied two cases of rebate strategies (mail-in rebates and channel rebates) in a two-level supply chain. By comparing them, the authors found that channel rebates are an effective tool for manufacturers to control retail prices. Considering retailers' risk aversion, Demirag, et al.[10] analyzed manufacturer's rebate decisions and the retailer's joint inventory and pricing decisions. Li, et al.[11] introduced the CVaR criterion to study channel rebates and penalty contracts with different degrees of risk aversion under stochastic demand.
Rebates for consumers include manufacturer rebates and retailer rebates. Manufacturer rebates refer to promotional offers where manufacturers provide rebates to consumers. This strategy has been widely studied and scholars have obtained many meaningful insights. For example, Khouja and Zhou[12] assumed that the estimated value of the rebate at the time of purchase decision is independent of the probability of redemption at the time of the redemption decision, and found that the consumer surplus decreases when a manufacturer offers a rebate. Yang, et al.[13] combined the manufacturer rebate with the manufacturer suggested retail price and proved that the optimal strategy of the manufacturer is determined by the slippage behavior of consumers and their loss aversion. Herrán and Sigue[14], however, found that manufacturers make higher profits when the coupon is redeemed than when it is not redeemed. Yang, et al.[15] studied two types of promotional models (mail-in rebates and retailer promotions), and showed that quantity discount contracts and buy-back contracts to coordinate the supply chain. Zhang[16] investigated the impacts of manufacturer rebates on the performance of the manufacturer and the retailer when the manufacturer sells the products in two different markets and found that, while it might seem counterintuitive, higher redemption rates are actually beneficial to channel members. Cao, et al.[17] studied optimal rebate strategies (both trade-in rebates and customer rebates with gift cards or cash coupons) from a business-to-consumer (B2C) platform perspective.
Retailer rebates refer to promotional activities where the retailer provides rebates to consumers. Many researchers have studied this issue. For example, Khouja, et al.[18] studied the promotional behavior of retailers offering gift cards and found that the profitability of retailers using gift cards depends on the repurchase rate of consumers and the redemption rate of the gift cards. Demirag[19] studied the pricing and ordering strategies of retailers with different risk preferences when retailers offer rebates to consumers in order to increase product sales. Yang, et al.[20] constructed a retailer rebates model based on economic order quantity, compared the rebates promotional activities with the everyday low price model, and concluded that the market positioning of retailers plays a vital role in the choice of their promotion strategies. Zhou, et al.[21] studied optimal strategies for an e-commerce provider. The results showed that, in contrast to the traditional supply chain model, the consumer surplus in a centralized structure is lower than that in a decentralized structure.
Much of the research on green product promotion has considered government subsidies to enterprises, with a few studies considering government subsidies on green products to customers. However, there are no extant studies considering rebate strategies in a green supply chain. The rebate strategy, as an effective promotional method, has been widely used in enterprise operations. However, most of the studies on rebate strategies only consider the supply chain model with a single product. In reality, though, competition between products is normal. Therefore, this study considers manufacturer rebates in a green supply chain in a competitive situation, focusing on the following questions: 1) How does the rebate strategy affect the decisions of channel members and the channel performance? 2) Which rebate strategies are preferred by manufacturers and retailers, respectively? 3) What kind of factors affect the strategic preference of channel members.

3 Assumptions and Notations

This study considers a two-echelon green supply chain consisting of one manufacturer and one retailer. The manufacturer produces two products (green products and conventional products) and needs to invest in green technology for producing the green products. The investment cost is 12s2, where the green level is s. It is assumed that green technology does not affect the marginal cost of green products. Therefore, without loss of generality, the marginal costs of conventional products and green products are assumed to be zero[22]. The manufacturer is the Stackelberg leader, and first decides on wholesale prices w1 (green products) and w2 (conventional products), the green level s, and the rebate value r. Then, the retailer determines the retail prices p1 (green products) and p2 (conventional products).
Referring to Xing, et al.[23], the demand functions are denoted as follows. Without rebates, the demands for green products and conventional products are q1=a1θ1a2p1+θ1p2+λs1θ1θ2 and q2=a2θ2a1p2+θ2p1θ2λs1θ1θ2, respectively. Here, a1 and a2 represent the potential market demands for green products and conventional products, respectively, θ1 is the substitution rate of green products for conventional products, and θ2 is the substitution rate of conventional products for green products; λ is the green sensitivity factor of consumers.
To simplify the calculation, the potential market demands and the substitution rate of products are assumed to be symmetric (a1=a2=a, θ1=θ2=θ). In the extended section, the models with asymmetric potential market demands and different product substitution rates are discussed.
1) When the manufacturer offers rebates to customers who purchase the green products, the demand for green products and conventional products are q1g=a(1θ)(p1tr)+θp2+λs1θ2 and q2g=a(1θ)p2+θ(p1tr)θλs1θ2, respectively, where t is the rebate sensitivity factor.
2) When the manufacturer offers rebates to customers who purchase conventional products, the demands for green products and conventional products are q1c=a(1θ)p1+θ(p2tr)+λs1θ2 and q2c=a(1θ)(p2tr)+θp1θλs1θ2, respectively.
The rebate frequency of manufacturer is β. The redemption rate of customers is k. To avoid trivial cases, it is assumed that k<t and λ(0,(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2kt(1β)). The superscripts g and c represent rebates for green products and conventional products, respectively. All proofs are given in the Appendix.

4 Model Analysis

4.1 No Rebates Model (Model N)

In this subsection, the model without manufacturer rebates is considered. The manufacturer decides the green level and the wholesale prices first, then the retailer decides the retail prices p1 and p2, respectively.
The profit functions for the manufacturer and the retailer are:
πm=w1q1+w2q212s2,
(1)
πr=(p1w1)q1+(p2w2)q2.
(2)
Using backward induction the following are obtained: w1=a(λ2θ+4θ24)2(λ2+4θ24), w2=a2, s=λa(1θ)λ2+4θ24, p1=3a(λ2θ+4θ24)4(λ2+4θ24), p2=3a4. Then, the profits of the manufacturer and the retailer are πm=a2(λ2+8θ8)8(λ2+4θ24) and πr=a2[λ48(1θ2)(λ2+4θ4)]16(λ2+4θ24)2, respectively.

4.2 Rebates for Green Products (Model G)

This subsection considers the model in which the manufacturer offers rebates to customers who purchase green products. The manufacturer is the Stackelberg-leader, and first determines the wholesale prices, green level, and rebate value. Next, the retailer determines the retail prices. The profit functions of channel members are as follows:
πmg=β(w1kr)q1g+(1β)w1q1+βw2q2g+(1β)w2q212s2,
(3)
πrg=(p1w1)[βq1g+(1β)q1]+(p2w2)[βq2g+(1β)q2].
(4)
The Hessian Matrix of πrg with respect to p1 and p2 is
Hrg=11θ2(22θ2θ2).
It is easy to verify that the Hessian matrix is negative definite. Therefore, solving the first order conditional equations, the optimal response functions of the retailer are obtained p1g=a2+w12+sλ2+βrt2, p2g=a2+w22. Substituting the optimal response functions into πmg, the Hessian matrix of πmg with respect to s, w1, w2, and r are obtained.
Hmg=12(1θ2)(2(θ21)βkλλθλβkλ2βkt(β2)β(k+t)βθ(k+t)λβ(k+t)22θθλβθ(k+t)2θ2).
(5)
Denote |Hmig| as the i-th order sub-determinant. Therefore,
|Hm1g|=1,|Hm2g|=βk4t(2β)(1θ2)βkλ24(θ21)2,
|Hm3g|=βA4(1θ2)3, and |Hm4g|=βA4(1θ2)3, where A=(2βkt2kt)λ2+(θ21)(βk28kt+βt2+6βkt). It is easy to know that |Hm1g|<0, |Hm2g|>0, |Hm3g|<0, and |Hm4g|>0. Therefore, the profit function of the manufacturer πmg is jointly concave in s, w1, w2, and r. Solving the first-order conditions, the optimal decisions of manufacturer are obtained: w1g=a(1θ2)[2k(4t3βtβk)+βθ(k2t2)]+2ktθλ2(β1)2A, w2g=a2, sg=2aktλ(1β)(1θ)A, rg=a(1θ2)(tk)(1θ)A. Substituting the manufacturer's optimal decisions into the retailer's reaction functions, optimal decisions of retailer are obtained: p1g=a(1θ2)[4k(6tβk5βt)+βθ(k2+2kt3t2)]+6ktθλ2(β1)4A, p2g=3a4. Then, the profit of the manufacturer and the retailer are, respectively:
πmg=a2β(k2+t2)(1θ2)+2kt[(1β)(λ278θ)1+βθ2]8A,πrg=a2β2(k4+t4)(θ21)2+k2t2(θ21)[8λ2(β1)(3β4)β2(13θ2128θ+51)+32(θ1)(4+βθ7β)]+4k2t2λ4(β1)2+4βkt(k2+t2)[(θ4+1)(3β4)+λ2(θ21)(β1)+2θ(4θ3β)]16A2.
Proposition 1  πmgβ>0, πrgβ>0, q1gβ>0, q2gβ<0, sgβ>0, rgβ>0, p1gβ>0, q1β<0, q2β>0, w1gβ>0.
The profits of channel members, the green level, the rebate value, the wholesale price, the retail price and the market demand for green products in the rebate period are positively correlated with the rebate frequency, while the market demand for green products outside the rebate period is negatively correlated with the rebate frequency. With the increase of rebate frequency, the differentiation of green products and conventional products is more significant, and the manufacturer attracts more customers to buy green products by improving the rebate value and green level. At the same time, the manufacturer raises her wholesale prices to ensure profitability, which leads to an increase in retail prices. However, consumers do not reduce their purchases in the rebate period, because the positive impacts of the increase in the rebate value and the green level dominate the negative impacts of the increase in retail price. Although consumers reduce their purchases of green products outside the rebate period and purchase conventional products instead, the impacts of manufacturer rebates on the aggregate demand for green products are positive and more significant than that for conventional products. So, the profits of channel members increase with the increase of rebate frequency.
Proposition 2  πmgk<0, πrgk<0, q1gk<0, q2gk>0, sgk<0, rgk<0, p1gk<0, w1gk<0.
Proposition 2 shows that the higher the redemption rate, the lower the rebate value. Thus, consumers get less surplus when they purchase green products than when they purchase conventional products, and eventually purchase conventional products. This reduces the demand for green products and also reduces the enthusiasm of manufacturers to invest in green technology, resulting in a decline in green levels. Ultimately, it reduces the profits of the manufacturer and the retailer.
Proposition 3  πmgt>0, πrgt>0, q1gt>0, q2gt<0, sgt>0, rgt>0, p1gt>0, w1gt>0.
Proposition 3 shows that the rebate sensitivity factor and the redemption rate have opposite effects on channel members. Specifically, with an increase in the rebate sensitivity factor, the manufacturer increases the rebate value and the green level, which is preferred by consumers. This leads to an increase in the sales of green products in the rebate period. Eventually, the profits of channel members are improved.

4.3 Rebates for Conventional Products (Model C)

This subsection considers a supply chain model in which the manufacturer offers rebates to customers who purchase conventional products. The manufacturer first decides the wholesale prices, the green level and the rebate value. Then, the retailer decides the retail prices. The profit functions of the manufacturer and the retailer are, respectively.
πmc=βw1q1c+(1β)w1q1+β(w2kr)q2c+(1β)w2q212s2,
(6)
πrc=β(p1w1)q1c+(1β)(p1w1)q1+β(p2w2)q2c+(1β)(p2w2)q2.
(7)
Similar to Model G, the optimal decisions can be obtained by backward induction, and are shown as follows:
w1c=2a{(1θ2)[8kt4βktβ(k+t)2]+2(β1)ktθλ2}C,
w2c=a{kλ2[βk4t+3βt+βθ2(tk)]+2(θ21)[βk2(2θ)+2(3β4)kt+βθt2]}C,
sc=aλ(θ1)(βk28kt+βt2+βθt2+6βkt+βθk22βθkt)C,
rc=a(1θ2)(kt)(λ24+4θ)C,
p1c=3a{(1θ2)[4kt(2β)β(k+t)2]+2ktθλ2(β1)}C,
p2c=a{(1θ2)[kt(2420β)+βk2(λ24)+βθ(k23t2+2kt)]+ktλ2[(5β6)+βθ2]}C,
where C=[β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2]λ24(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)].
The profits of the manufacturer and the retailer are, respectively:
πmc=a2β(1θ2)(kt)2+2kt(1β)[a2(λ28)+8θ]2Cπrc=a2(θ21){4λ2(k2+t2)(β1)+32k2t2[λ2+4β2θ+(θ1)(βθ7β+4)]+8βk2t2λ2[θ(1β)84β]}+(θ21)2[4βkt(k2+t2)(3β4)+β2(k4+t4)]+2k2t2[2λ4(β1)2β2(θ1)(13θ+51)]C2.
Proposition 4  πmcβ>0, scβ<0, rcβ>0, w1cβ<0, w2cβ>0, q1cβ<0, q2cβ>0, p1cβ<0, p2cβ>0.
Proposition 4 shows that the manufacturer's profit, the rebate value, the demand for conventional products in the rebate period, the wholesale price and the retail price of conventional products are positively related to the rebate frequency. The wholesale price and retail price of green products are negatively correlated with the rebate frequency. Proposition 1 and Proposition 4 show that it is beneficial for the manufacturer to offer rebates, regardless of the type of products. However, unlike with Model G, the rebates for conventional products increase the demand for conventional products and inhibit the demand of green products, so the manufacturer has no incentive to invest in green technology, resulting in a decline in the green level.
Proposition 5  πmck<0, p1ck>0, p2ck<0, sck>0, rck<0, w1ck>0, w2ck<0, q1ck>0, q2ck<0.
Proposition 5 shows that the rebate value, the wholesale price, the retail price and the demand of conventional products in the rebate period decrease with the increase of the redemption rate, while the green level and demand for green products in the rebate period increase with the increase of the redemption rate. This demonstrates that the higher the redemption rate of consumers, the greater the promotional costs for manufacturer, which reduces the rebate value and lead to a decline in the demand for conventional products in the rebate period. To maintain margins, the manufacturer increases the green level and wholesale price of green products, thus improving the market competitiveness of green products. However, with the increase of the redemption rate, the slippage effect is not significant, and the gains for green products cannot compensate for the losses for conventional products, which leads to a decline in the manufacturer's profit.
Proposition 6  πmct>0, p1ct<0, p2ct>0, sct<0, rct>0, w1ct<0, w2ct>0, q1ct<0, q2ct>0, q1t>0, q2t<0.
Proposition 6 shows that the higher the rebate sensitivity factor of conventional products, the lower the green level of green products, and the less beneficial the sales of green products in the rebate period are. However, the higher the rebate sensitivity factor of conventional products, the more competitive the conventional products are, which ultimately leads to an increase in the manufacturer's profit.
Because the retailer's profit in Model C is complex, the sensitivity analysis is not feasible. It is discussed through numerical analysis. The parameter values are given as follows: a=10, θ=0.4, λ=0.6, The results are shown in Figure 1.
Figure 1 The effects of rebate parameters on the retailer's profit in Model C

Full size|PPT slide

Figure 1 shows that the profit of the retailer increases with an increase in the rebate frequency and decreases with an increase in the redemption rate in Model C. These trends become increasingly obvious with the increase in the rebate sensitivity factor. In other words, the higher rebate sensitivity factor aggravates the impacts of rebate frequency and redemption rate.

5 Strategies Analysis

5.1 The Effects of Rebate Strategies

This subsection discusses the effects of rebate strategies on the performances of channel members. Firstly, the effects of rebates for green products are explored, and the results are shown in Table 1.
Table 1 The effects of rebates for green products
w1w1g w2w2g p1p1g p2p2g ssg πmπmg πrπrg
() (0) () (0) () () ()
Table 1 shows that: 1) The wholesale price and retail price of green products in Model N are lower than those in Model G. 2) Rebates for green products have no effects on the optimal decisions for conventional products. 3) Although the wholesale price and the retail price of green products increase in Model G, the rebate strategy increases the demand for green products, ultimately improving the profits of channel members. 4) The green level in Model G is higher than that in Model N. This shows that rebates for green products are not only beneficial to channel members, but also beneficial to the environment.
Secondly, the effects of rebates for conventional products are discussed, and the results are shown in Table 2.
Table 2 The effects of rebates for conventional products
w1w1c w2w2c p1p1c p2p2c ssc πmπmc
(+) () (+) () (+) ()
Table 2 shows that, 1) The retail prices and wholesale prices of green products are lower in Model C than those in Model N. 2) The wholesale prices and retail prices of conventional products are higher in Model C than those in Model N. 3) Consistent with Model G, the manufacturer's profit in Model C is higher than that in Model N. 4) As the competitiveness of green products declines, the manufacturer reduces her investment in green levels to reduce the loss of profits, which eventually leads to the decline of green levels.
Because the retailer's profit in Model C is complex, the sign of πrπrc could not be judged by theoretical analysis. It is discussed by numerical analysis. The parameter values are given as follow, a=10, θ=0.4, λ=0.6, the results are shown in Figure 2.
Figure 2 The effects of rebates on retailer's profit in Model C

Full size|PPT slide

Figure 2 shows that, 1) The profit for retailers is higher in Model C than that in Model N. 2) The difference in the retailer's profits between Model N and Model C increases with the increase of the rebate frequency and decreases with the increase in the redemption rate, and the increase of the rebate sensitivity factor widens this gap.

5.2 Rebate Strategy Preference

This subsection discusses the strategic preferences of channel members. First, the influence of the redemption rate on the rebate strategy preference of channel members is considered, and the parameter values are given as follows: β=0.3, t=0.8, λ=0.6, a=10, θ=0.4. The results are shown in Figure 3. Second, the influence of the rebate sensitivity factor on the rebate strategy preference of channel members is considered, and the value of the parameters are given as follows: β=0.3, k=0.2, λ=0.6, a=10, θ=0.4. The results are shown in Figure 4. Third, the influence of the rebate frequency on the rebate strategy preference of channel members is considered, and the value of the parameters are given as follows: k=0.3, t=0.5, λ=0.6, a=10, θ=0.4 and the results are shown in Figure 5.
Figure 3 The influence of k on the rebate strategy preference

Full size|PPT slide

Figure 4 The influence of t on the rebate strategy preference

Full size|PPT slide

Figure 5 The influence of β on the rebate strategy preference

Full size|PPT slide

Figures 35 show that, 1) the redemption rate, the rebate sensitivity factor, and the rebate frequency do not change the strategies preference of channel members. Both members prefer the rebate strategy for green products, which not only helps to increase the profits of channel members, but also helps to improve the green level. 2) The advantages of rebate strategies for green products are more significant with the decrease of the redemption rate and the increases of the rebate sensitivity factor and the rebate frequency. Moreover, the impact of different rebate strategies on the retailer is more significant than that on the manufacturer.

6 Model Extension

Based on the previous analysis, this section expands the model from the following two aspects: 1) The potential market demands are asymmetric, being a1 and a2 for green products and conventional products, respectively; 2) The substitution rates are asymmetric, i.e. θ1θ2.

6.1 Asymmetric Potential Market Demands

The demands for green products and conventional products without rebates are, respectively: q^1=a1θa2p1+θp2+λs1θ2 and q^2=a2θa1p2+θp1θλs1θ2. The demands for green products and conventional products with the rebate strategy for green products are, respectively: q^1g=a1θa2(p1tr)+θp2+λs1θ2 and q^2g=a2θa1p2+θ(p1tr)θλs1θ2. The profit functions of the manufacturer and the retailer with the rebates for green products are, respectively:
π^mg=β(w1kr)q^1g+(1β)w1q^1+βw2q^2g+(1β)w2q^212s2,
(8)
π^rg=(p1w1)[βq^1g+(1β)q^1]+(p2w2)[βq^2g+(1β)q^2].
(9)
The demands for green products and conventional products with the rebate strategy for conventional products are, respectively: q^1c=a1θa2p1+θ(p2tr)+λs1θ2 and q^2c=11θ2[a2θa1(p2tr)+θp1θλs]. The profit functions of the manufacturer and the retailer with the rebates for conventional products are, respectively:
π^mc=βw1q^1c+(1β)w1q^1+β(w2kr)q^2c+(1β)w2q^212s2,
(10)
π^rc=β(p1w1)q^1c+(1β)(p1w1)q^1+β(p2w2)q^2c+(1β)(p2w2)q^2.
(11)

6.2 Asymmetric Product Substitution Rate

The demands for green products and conventional products without rebate are, respectively: q¯1=aθ1ap1+θ1p2+λs1θ1θ2 and q¯2=aθ2ap2+θ2p1θ2λs1θ1θ2. The demands for green products and conventional products with the rebate strategy for green products are, respectively: q¯1g=aθ1a(p1tr)+θ1p2+λs1θ1θ2 and q¯2g=aθ2ap2+θ2(p1tr)θ2λs1θ1θ2. The profit functions of the manufacturer and the retailer with the rebates for green product are, respectively:
π¯mg=β(w1kr)q¯1g+(1β)w1q¯1+βw2q¯2g+(1β)w2q¯212s2,
(12)
π¯rg=(p1w1)[βq¯1g+(1β)q¯1]+(p2w2)[βq¯2g+(1β)q¯2].
(13)
The demands for green products and conventional products under the rebate strategy for conventional products are, respectively: q¯1c=aθ1ap1+θ1(p2tr)+λs1θ1θ2 and q¯2c=11θ1θ2[aθ2a(p2tr)+θ2p1θ2λs]. The profit functions of the manufacturer and the retailer with the rebates for conventional products are, respectively:
π¯mc=βw1q¯1g+(1β)w1q¯1+β(w2kr)q¯2g+(1β)w2q¯212s2,
(14)
π¯rc=(p1w1)[βq¯1g+(1β)q¯1]+(p2w2)[βq¯2g+(1β)q¯2].
(15)

6.3 Numerical Analysis

In this subsection, the extended models are discussed by numerical analysis. First, the influence of asymmetric potential market demands on the rebate strategy preference of channel members is considered. The parameter values are given as follows: θ=0.4, k=0.3, t=0.5, β=0.7, λ=0.6, a2=10, with the results shown in Figure 6.
Figure 6 The influence of a1 on the rebate strategy preference

Full size|PPT slide

Figure 6 shows that, 1) with the increasing of potential market demand for green products, the profit difference of channel members under different rebate strategies first decreases and then increases. 2) When the demand for green products is small, it is more favorable for channel members to choose the rebate strategy for conventional products. However, when the potential market of green products is high, channel members prefer the rebate strategy for green products. 3) The influence of a1 on the profit difference for retailer is more significant than that on the profit difference for manufacturer.
Second, the influence of asymmetric product substitution rates on the rebate strategies preference of channel members is discussed. The parameter values are given as follows k=0.3, t=0.5, β=0.7, λ=0.6, a=10, θ2=0.4. The results are shown in Figure 7.
Figure 7 The influence of θ1 on the rebate strategy preference

Full size|PPT slide

Figure 7 shows that, as θ1 increases, the profit difference between channel members with different rebate strategies first decreases and then increases. When θ1 is small, the rebates for green products decrease the actual price of green products, thereby attracting the consumers in the potential market of green products, ultimately leading to an increase in channel members' profits. When θ1 is large, green products have a high substitution value for conventional products, and then the rebates for green products are attractive for customers both from the conventional products market and green products market, which increase the market demand for green products, ultimately increasing the profits of channel members. In summary, when θ1 is small or large, the advantage of rebates for green products is more significant, but asymmetric product substitution rates do not change the channel members' rebate strategy preferences.

7 Conclusion

This study constructs a green supply chain model composed of one manufacturer and one retailer, and analyzes two rebate strategies for manufacturers simultaneously producing green products and conventional products. The differences between the rebate strategies are compared, with the following results.
1) In the green supply chain, the rebate strategies help increase the profits of channel members. Specifically, the more significant the slippage effects are (the smaller the k or the larger the t), the more beneficial the rebate strategies are, and the effects of the rebate strategies are more significant for the retailer than they are for the manufacturer. In addition, the rebate strategy for green products is more beneficial to channel members and to the environment than the rebate strategy for conventional products.
2) In Model G, the higher the rebate sensitivity factor is, the higher the green level is. This means that the channel members can improve the rebate sensitivity factor through promotions and achieve a win-win situation in terms of protecting the environment and enhancing their profits. However, in Model C, the increase in the rebate sensitivity factor reduces the green level. In this case, the channel members should be cautious about promoting rebate strategies.
3) When the potential market demands of products are asymmetric, it is more beneficial for channel members to choose products with higher potential market demand to employ the rebate strategy. This shows that the potential market demand is an important factor affecting the choice of the rebate strategy for channel members.
Although this study provides important conclusions, there are still many areas that call for further study. 1) This study only considers manufacturer rebate promotions and does not consider the rebate strategy of retailers. 2) It is assumed that consumers are homogeneous, and the heterogeneity of consumers is not considered. 3) This study mainly assumes a deterministic market demand, and does not consider the uncertainty of market demand caused by consumers' unfamiliarity with green products.

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1
πmgβ=a2kt(kt)2(1θ)3(θ+1)A2>0,
πrgβ=8a2k2t2(kt)2(1β)(θ1)4(θ+1)2A3>0,
q1gβ=at(k+t)(kt)2(θ1)2(θ+1)A2>0,
q2gβ=aθt(k+t)(kt)2(θ1)2(θ+1)A2<0,
sgβ=2aktλ(kt)2(θ1)2(θ+1)A2>0,
rgβ=a(θ21)(kt)(θ1)[2ktλ2(1θ2)(k2+t2+6kt)]A2.
Because 0<λ<(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2kt(1β), then 0<2ktλ2<11β(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]. So, 2ktλ2(1θ2)(k2+t2+6kt)<(1θ2)(kt)21β<0, it means rgβ>0.
p1gβ=2akt(kt)(θ1)2(θ+1)[kλ2(1θ2)(k+3t)]A2.
Because 0<λ<(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2kt(1β), then 0<kλ2<(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2t(1β). So, kλ2(1θ2)(k+3t)<(1θ2)(kt)[6tβ(k+5t)]2t(1β)<0, it means p1gβ>0.
q1β=2akt(kt)(θ1)(kθ23tk+3θ2t+tλ2)A2<0,
q2β=2akθt(kt)(θ1)(kθ23tk+3θ2t+tλ2)A2>0,
w1gβ=2akt(kt)(θ1)2(θ+1)(2kθ22t2k+kλ2+2θ2t)A2>0.
Proof of Proposition 2
πmgk=a2βt(k2t2)(β1)(θ1)3(θ+1)A2<0,
πrgk=8a2βkt2(k2t2)(β1)2(θ1)4(θ+1)2A3<0,
q1gk=at(β1)(θ1){2t2(1β)λ2(1θ2)[8t2β(5t2+k2+2kt)]}A2.
Because 0<λ<(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2kt(1β), then 2t2(1β)λ2<tk(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]. So 2t2(1β)λ2(1θ2)[8t2β(5t2+k2+2kt)]<β(1θ2)(k2t2)(k+t)k<0, it means q1gk<0.
q2gk=θq1gk>0.
sgk=2aβtλ(k2t2)(β1)(θ1)2(θ+1)A2<0.
rgk=a(θ1)2(θ+1){2t2(1β)λ2(1θ2)[8t2β(7t2k2+2kt)]}A2.
Because 0<λ<(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2kt(1β), then 2t2(1β)λ2<tk(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]. So 2t2(1β)λ2(1θ2)[8t2β(7t2k2+2kt)]<(1θ2)β(k2t2)(tk)k<0, it means rgk<0.
p1gk=aβt(θ1)2(θ+1){(1β)2k2λ2(θ21)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]}A2.
Because 0<λ<(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2kt(1β), then 2k2(1β)λ2<kt(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]. So (1β)2k2λ2(θ21)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]<1t(1θ2)(k2t2)[6tβ(k+5t)]<0, it means p1gk<0. w1gk=p1gk<0.
Proof of Proposition 3
πmgt=a2βk(k2t2)(β1)(θ1)3(θ+1)A2>0,
πrgt=8a2βk2t(k2t2)(β1)2(β1)4(θ+1)2A3>0,
q1gt=ak(β1)(θ1){2t2(1β)λ2(1θ2)[8t2β(5t2+k2+2kt)]}A2.
Because 0<λ<(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2kt(1β), then 2t2(1β)λ2<tk(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]. So 2t2(1β)λ2(1θ2)[8t2β(5t2+k2+2kt)]<β(1θ2)(k2t2)(k+t)k<0, it means q1gt>0. q2gt=q1gt<0.
rgt=a(θ1)2(θ+1){2k2(1β)λ2(1θ2)[8t2β(7t2k2+2kt)]}A2.
Because 0<λ<(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2kt(1β), then 2k2(1β)λ2<kt(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]. So 2k2(1β)λ2(1θ2)[8t2β(7t2k2+2kt)]<(1θ2)β(k2t2)(tk)t<0, it means rgk<0.
sgt=2aβkλ(k2t2)(β1)(θ1)2(θ+1)A2>0.
p1gt=aβk(θ1)2(θ+1){(1β)2k2λ2(θ21)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]}A2.
Because 0<λ<(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]2kt(1β), then 2k2(1β)λ2<kt(1θ2)[8ktβ(k2+t2+6kt)]. So (1β)2k2λ2(θ21)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]<1t(1θ2)(k2t2)[6tβ(k+5t)]<0, it means p1gt>0. w1gt=p1gt>0.
Proof of Proposition 4
πmcβ=a2kt(θ21)(kt)2(λ2+4θ4)2C2>0,scβ=8akθtλ(θ21)(kt)2(λ2+4θ4)C2<0,rcβ=aC2(θ21)(kt)(λ2+4θ4){[(1θ2)(k+t)2+4kt(1+θ2)]λ2+4(θ21)(k2+6kt+t2)}<0,w1cβ=4akθtλ2(θ21)(kt)2(λ2+4θ4)C2<0,w2cβ=4akt(θ21)(k2t2)(λ2+4θ4)(4θ2+λ24)C2>0,q1cβ=aθt(θ21)(kt)2(λ2+4θ4)(4k+4t+kλ2tλ2)C2<0,q2cβ=at(θ21)(λ24)(k+t)(kt)2(λ2+4θ4)C2>0,p1cβ=6akθtλ2(θ21)(kt)2(λ2+4θ4)C2<0,p2cβ=2akt(θ21)(k2+2kt3t2)[16(θ1)2(θ+1)+λ2(4θ2+4θ+λ28)]C2>0.
Proof of Proposition 5
πmck=a2βt(θ21)(k2t2)(β1)(λ2+4θ4)2C2<0,p1ck=6aβθtλ2(θ21)(k2t2)(β1)(λ2+4θ4)C2>0,p2ck=aβtC2(1θ2)(λ2+4θ4){[λ24(1θ2)][β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]βθ2(kt)2λ2}.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2βθ2(kt)2,
so [λ24(1θ2)][β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]βθ2(kt)2λ2>0, it means p2ck<0.
sck=8aβθtλ(θ21)(k2t2)(θ1)(λ2+4θ4)C2>0,rck=a(1θ2)(λ2+4θ4){βθ2(kt)2λ2+[λ24(1θ2)][β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2]}C2.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2]βθ2(kt)2+β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2,
so [βθ2(kt)2+β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2]λ2+4(θ21)[β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2]>0, it means rck<0.
w1ck=4aβθtλ2(θ21)(k2t2)(β1)(λ2+4θ4)C2>0,w2ck=aβtC2(θ21)(λ2+4θ4){[λ24(1θ2)][β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4(k2+t2)]+βθ2(kt)2λ2}.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4k24t2]β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4k24t2+βθ2(kt)2,
so [β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4k24t2+βθ2(kt)2]λ24(1θ2)[β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4k24t2]>0, it means w2ck<0.
q1ck=aθtC2(β1)(λ2+4θ4){[β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2+βθ2(kt)2]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]}.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2+βθ2(kt)2,
so [β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2+βθ2(kt)2]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]>0, it means q1ck>0.
q2ck=atC2(β1)(λ2+4θ4){[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2βθ2(k2+2kt3t2)]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]}.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2βθ2(k2+2kt3t2),
so [β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2βθ2(k2+2kt3t2)]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]>0, it means q2ck<0.
Proof of Proposition 6
πmct=a2βk(θ21)(k2t2)(β1)(λ2+4θ4)2C2>0,p1ct=6aβθkλ2(θ21)(k2t2)(β1)(λ2+4θ4)C2<0,p2ct=aβkC2(θ21)(λ2+4θ4){[β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2βθ2(kt)2]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]}.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2βθ2(kt)2,
so [β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2βθ2(kt)2]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)2k26t2]>0, it means p2ct>0.
sct=8aβθkλ(θ21)(k2t2)(β1)(λ2+4θ4)C2<0,rct=a(θ21)(λ2+4θ4){βθ2(kt)2λ2+[λ2+4(θ21)][β(7k2t2+2kt)8k2]}C2.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(7k2t2+2kt)8k2]β(7k2t2+2kt)8k2+βθ2(kt)2,
so βθ2(kt)2λ2+[λ2+4(θ21)][β(7k2t2+2kt)8k2]>0, it means rct>0.
w1ct=4aβθkλ2(θ21)(k2t2)(β1)(λ2+4θ4)C2<0,w2ct=aβkC2(θ21)(λ2+4θ4){[λ2+4(θ21)][β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4(k2+t2)]+βθ2(kt)2λ2}.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4k24t2]β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4k24t2+βθ2(kt)2,
so [β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4k24t2+βθ2(kt)2]λ2+4(θ21)[β(3k2+3t2+2kt)4k24t2]>0, it means w2ct>0.
q1ct=akθC2(β1)(λ2+4θ4){[β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2+βθ2(kt)2]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]}.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2+βθ2(kt)2,
so [β(7t2k2+2kt)8t2+βθ2(kt)2]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]>0, it means q1ct<0.
q2ct=akC2(β1)(λ2+4θ4){[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2βθ2(k2+2kt3t2)]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]}.
Because
λ<(1θ2)[β(k2+t2+6kt)8kt]2kt(β1)<4(1θ2)[β(k+t)24kt(2β)]β(k+t)24kt(2β)βθ2(kt)2<4(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2βθ2(k2+2kt3t2),
so [β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2βθ2(k2+2kt3t2)]λ24(1θ2)[β(k2+5t2+2kt)8t2]>0, it means q2ct>0.
Proof of the results in Table 1 and Table 2.
Because the optimal decisions and profits of channel members in the model without manufacturer rebates are the special outcomes in the models with manufacturer rebates while β=0. So, according to Proposition 1 and Proposition 4, we can easily verify the results in Table 1 and Table 2.

References

1
International Energy Agency-IEA. CO2 emissions from fuel combustion 2019. Available online: https://www.doc88.com/p-10129066441338.html. Accessed 19 April 2022.
2
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Climate change 2007 synthes is report. Available online: https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/02/ar4syrfullreport.pdf. Accessed 12 December 2019.
3
Melnyk S A, Smith R T. Green manufacturing. Computer automated systems of the society of manufacturing engineers. Dearborn, Michigan, USA, 1996.
4
Nastu P. GM plant eliminates waste, goes landfill-free. Available online: https://www.environmentalleader.com/2007/08/gm-plant-eliminates-waste-goes-landfill-free/. Accessed 20 April 2022.
5
European Commission. Europeans' attitudes towards the issue of sustainable consumption and production. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/environment/eussd/pdf/FL256summary.pdf. Accessed 19 April 2022.
6
Chen X, Li C L, Rhee B D, et al. The impact of manufacturer rebates on supply chain profits. Nav Res Log, 2007, 54 (6): 667- 680.
7
Taylor T A. Supply chain coordination under channel rebates with sales effort effects. Management Science, 2002, 48 (8): 992- 1007.
8
Ha A Y, Shang W X, Wang Y J. Manufacturer rebate competition in a supply chain with a common retailer. Production and Operations Management, 2017, 26 (11): 2122- 2136.
9
Muzaffar A, Malik M N, Rashid A. Rebate mechanism for the manufacturer in two-level supply chains. Asia Pacific Management Review, 2018, 23 (4): 301- 309.
10
Demirag O C, Chen Y H, Li J B. Customer and retailer rebates under risk aversion. International Journal of Production Economics, 2011, 133 (2): 736- 750.
11
Li J B, Yu N, Liu Z X. Research on two different supply chain rebates and penalty contracts with Cvar criterion. Systems Engineering — Theory & Practice, 2015, 35 (7): 1666- 1677.
12
Khouja M, Zhou J. The effect of delayed incentives on supply chain profits and consumer surplus. Production and Operations Management, 2010, 19 (2): 172- 197.
13
Yang S, Munson C L, Chen B. Using MSRP to enhance the ability of rebates to control distribution channels. European Journal of Operational Research, 2010, 205 (1): 127- 135.
14
Herrán G M, Sigue S P. Trade deals and/or on-package coupons. European Journal of Operational Research, 2015, 241 (2): 541- 554.
15
Yang S, Munson C L, Chen B, et al. Coordinating contracts for supply chains that market with mail-in rebates and retailer promotions. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 2015, 66 (12): 2025- 2036.
16
Zhang J Q. The benefits of consumer rebates: A strategy for gray market deterrence. European Journal of Operational Research, 2016, 251 (2): 509- 521.
17
Cao K, Xu X Y, Bian Y W, et al. Optimal trade-in strategy of business-to-consumer platform with dualformat retailing model. Omega, 2019, 82, 181- 192.
18
Khouja M, Pan J M, Brian T R, et al. Analysis of free gift card program effectiveness. Journal of Retailing, 2011, 87 (4): 444- 461.
19
Demirag O C. Performance of weather-conditional rebates under different risk preferences. Omega, 2013, 41 (6): 1053- 1067.
20
Yang S, Liao Y, Shi C V, et al. Joint optimization of ordering and promotional strategies for retailers: Rebates vs EDLP. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 2015, 90, 46- 53.
21
Zhou Y W, Cao B, Tang Q S, et al. Pricing and rebate strategies for an e-shop with a cashback website. European Journal of Operational Research, 2017, 262 (1): 108- 122.
22
Ghosh D, Shah J. A comparative analysis of greening policies across supply chain structures. International Journal of Production Economics, 2012, 135 (2): 568- 583.
23
Xing W, Zou J, Liu T L. Integrated or decentralized: an analysis of channel structure for green products. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 2017, 112, 20- 34.
PDF(270 KB)

346

Accesses

0

Citation

Detail

Sections
Recommended

/